If you have been following politics long enough, it would not surprise you that unpopular candidates win elections now and then. But what might surprise you is the fact that mathematics can explain this phenomenon quite deterministically.
The underlying effect here is known as the Asymmetric Dominance Effect. I have already written a layman-friendly non-technical essay on this topic; a precursor to this essay. So, if you are interested, check it out.
In this essay, I will be illustrating the mathematics behind the asymmetric dominance effect using a simplified (yet realistic) example. Following this, I will also go on to demonstrate a mathematical approach that one could use to neutralize the asymmetric dominance effect. Let us begin.
This essay is supported by Generatebg
Unpopular Candidates Win Elections. But How?
Let us consider a hypothetical election scenario involving two candidates: A and B in the town of Mathville. You see, 48% of the folks in Mathville like candidate A, whereas 49% of the folks like candidate B.
So, in a head-to-head election between these two candidates, you could expect candidate B to win. So far, so good. But just like how there are minority political parties in the real world, there exists a seemingly irrelevant underdog candidate: C in Mathville as well. 3% of the folks like this candidate.
In an election involving these three candidates, you could expect candidate B to still win over candidate A by a slim margin and candidate C to secure the minority of the votes. But in the election that took place in Mathville, candidate A actually got 49% of the votes, whereas candidate B got 48% of the votes and candidate C got 3% of the votes.
So, in essence, the unpopular candidate won the election just after we added a seemingly irrelevant underdog candidate to the mix. That’s interesting, isn’t it? Let us find out what is going on underneath this strange phenomenon.
The Asymmetric Dominance Effect in Full Swing
Before we even start analysing the problem, let us make one thing clear. Candidate C was never going to win the election. You know that; I know that; everybody in Mathville probably knows that. Why this fact is important for us is as follows:
When the people of Mathville voted, they were collectively answering the question of:
“Should candidate A win or candidate B win?”
and NOT
“Should candidate A or B or C win?”
What is going on here is that the presence of the irrelevant alternative C somehow skewed the election in candidate A’s favour, even though the majority liked candidate B. This is the asymmetric dominance effect in full swing.
You will shortly see (mathematically), how votes involving more than two candidates can produce paradoxical outcomes. The irrelevant alternative actually plays a key role, and the majority does not always win. There exists an ambiguity as to how this is possible because we are asking the wrong question.
The Math Behind the Asymmetric Dominance Effect
The question we are asking is binary in nature: yes or no; either/or. If most people prefer a candidate and that candidate loses, then we have to look at our voting system. If we look at our current system carefully, we could arrive at this very important observation:
Our voting system does not allow for people who voted for candidate C to express their preference of candidate B over A or vice-versa.
In other words, the system neglects relevant and decisive information before the final result. If this is too abstract for you, let me help you out graphically. Consider a different voting system, where the people don’t vote for a candidate binarily, but instead, express their order of preference of the available candidates as follows:
Now, if we were to conduct the election using this new system in Mathville, we would get a result similar to the following distribution:
Now, our previous voting system considers only the first preference. If you tally the percentages based on just the first ranked candidates, you would get exactly the same result as before. But with the new system, we have more information.
Using this to our advantage, pay attention to all of the ranking combinations in which candidate B comes in front of candidate A. That would be combinations 3, 4, and 6. Now, add these percentages together and you will get a total of 50.9%. This means that 49.1% of people prefer candidate A (100–50.9 = 49.1%).
In other words, the majority of the folks of Mathville prefer candidate B, but candidate A wins because we only consider each voter’s first preference. By doing this, we let the irrelevant alternative (candidate C) skew the election in candidate A’s favour.
Now that we have identified what the issue is, how can we solve this? Well, it turns out that this is an already solved problem, and we have eighteenth-century French mathematician, Jean-Charles de Borda to thank for that.
Unpopular Candidates Win Elections. Applied Math Can Prevents This.
Borda’s approach treats the election as an input-output-machine. We feed in individual voters’ preferences and expect the public’s will as output in return. We could add a few layers of abstraction that consider all of the information, unlike our previous system. Let us see how.
First, let us consider the same distribution (from before) based on voter ranking as follows:
Next, as per Borda’s simple and beautiful system, we can award each candidate points as per their placement in the rankings. The rules of this approach are as follows:
1. For each ranking combination, award 2 points for the first place, 1 point for the second place, and 0 points for the third place.
2. Next, multiply the number of points per candidate for each combination by the respective fraction of total voters who chose the combination.
3. Finally, sum up the products for each combination to arrive at the Borda count for each candidate.
For example, based on the above distribution, we would compute the Borda count for candidate A as follows:
Similarly, we could compute the Borda count for the other two candidates as follows:
There we go. Based on the Borda count, we no longer have a paradoxical election result, and candidate B would win the election!
Final Comments
Borda came up with his system in the year 1770. The French Academy of Sciences used his system to elect its members for two whole decades before Napoleon Bonaparte became the president and “opted” to use his own system instead.
Voting systems are never straightforward. In fact, the very notion of “public opinion” might not even exist. I have covered this issue in detail in my essay on why polls mislead most of the time. If you are interested, check it out.
When it comes to the level of complexity of today’s elections, I am not sure how practical it would be to implement the Borda count system. However, as things are, unpopular candidates win now and then, and the asymmetric dominance effect is clearly in play.
Reference and credit: Jordon Ellenberg and Jean-Charles de Borda.
Thanks to Elder Taoist and William Crendal for requesting this essay.
If you’d like to get notified when interesting content gets published here, consider subscribing.
Further reading that might interest you:
- Newcomb’s Paradox – A Challenge To Game Theory
- How To Use Science To Win At Rock-Paper-Scissors?
- Infinite Regress: How To Really Understand It?
If you would like to support me as an author, consider contributing on Patreon.
Comments